The opposition is
growing
A couple
of blogs back I said that imposing a bed tax on informal
accommodation mostly offered through peer-to-peer web sites is a bad idea. My reasons: it is a targeted tax, it ignores
the fact that the accommodation capacity made available through platforms like
Airbnb is already paid for by rates and user charges; and visitors who pay to
use spare rooms or backyard cottages can be expected to have no more impact on
public services than family members or friends who don’t pay.
The informal sector provides low cost capacity at the
margins to support the expansion of the visitor industry, thereby reducing
uncertainty for commercial investors in tourism. The Auckland Chamber of Commerce made the additional
point that Airbnb, Book-a-Bach, and the like cater for visitors who might not
otherwise visit Auckland. So I struggle
to understand why the Council should take this stand, especially when the idea
of a bed tax on commercial accommodation is already
under attack.
The more I read about the policy the less I like it. Here
are four reasons.
1 A Poorly Designed Tax
The tax is complicated, intrusive, and consequently inefficient. It is being added to the rates bill, confounding what is otherwise a generally straightforward levy based on the capital value of property. This confusing revenue collection process by local government will impose new administrative costs for little gain.
The Council evidently identified between 8,000 and 12,000
households renting out rooms or properties, and has managed to target 1,100 of
them. It sent out two letters to those
it identified and set the rate depending on whether the owners replied or not[1]. Too bad if you were away at the time, or
failed to clear your mail, or simply thought it was all a bit silly, and didn’t
reply. The result: a higher rate set as punishment. The tax is complicated, intrusive, and consequently inefficient. It is being added to the rates bill, confounding what is otherwise a generally straightforward levy based on the capital value of property. This confusing revenue collection process by local government will impose new administrative costs for little gain.
Oh, if you only rent out one room or let rooms for fewer than 29 nights in a year you won’t have to pay. Good luck to the Council in enforcing that. I wonder if the cost in wages (and political capital) is worth the effort.
2 Compounding the tax impost
The new rate is actually a tax, a tax on providers rather than on consumers. Bed-taxes are an expensive form of revenue collection compared, with say, a visitor levy collected at port or airport. And the amount they might generate is trivial in the bigger picture: GST, rates on commercial tourism properties, and income tax derived from the hospitality sector already contribute substantially to government revenue. [2]
In the case of the informal accommodation sector, the revenue received by owners
who use booking platforms to attract short-stay visitors to their spare room, empty
cottage, or holdiay home is already captured in the income tax net. They also pay
additional user charges for the services consumed through their property. The new rate is actually a tax, a tax on providers rather than on consumers. Bed-taxes are an expensive form of revenue collection compared, with say, a visitor levy collected at port or airport. And the amount they might generate is trivial in the bigger picture: GST, rates on commercial tourism properties, and income tax derived from the hospitality sector already contribute substantially to government revenue. [2]
The bed tax is inequitable in a number of ways. Owners are treated differently from those who let rooms or cottages to long-stay tenants or outside formal booking platforms, or anyone else running a small business from a residential area. The use of spare capacity in the housing sector, a sector in which many households are over-invested, is penalised when many would think it should be encouraged.
Inequity is compounded when the providers of bed and
breakfast services are working to make ends meet with a little additional
income. There are many households in
Auckland having to do this with long-term sub-lets. Why should those that take the short-term
rental path instead be treated differently?
3 A new ratepayer business subsidy
According to the Mayor, the revenue raised by bed taxes
generally (including from AirBnB operators) is used to fund Auckland Tourism,
Events, and Economic Development (ATEED), Auckland Council’s
development agency.
ATEED incurs spends on marketing and promotions to boost demand
for selected commercial goods, services (including underwriting events), and sectors. This may be justifiable for emerging sectors,
to support innovation, and even for city branding.
But these are items that might be more appropriately charged
to general revenues of the Council in a clearly transparent, politically
contestable process. Beyond that, initiatives
to promote established sectors like tourism may be best funded by direct
charges on the beneficiaries. The
capacity to fund would then be based on capacity to deliver, rather than on coercion;
on revenue earned rather than on tax- based subsidies.
4 An Anti-Competitive Move
Finally, the new bed tax appears to be an anti-competitive move by the council. The Mayor says “it was introduced after representatives from the hotel and motel industry approached him about Airbnb’s advantages”. Hmmm – are these the same interests benefiting from the subsidies ATEED passes on? It begins to look like they want it both ways.
Finally, the new bed tax appears to be an anti-competitive move by the council. The Mayor says “it was introduced after representatives from the hotel and motel industry approached him about Airbnb’s advantages”. Hmmm – are these the same interests benefiting from the subsidies ATEED passes on? It begins to look like they want it both ways.
Either way, I question the role of local government in manipulating rates to manipulate the market.
Informal accommodation has always been around. It is better organised today, and demand has
grown as a result of innovative, web-based booking systems – which, incidentally are increasingly relied
on by hotel and motel operators. The new platforms are also raising standards through user and provider feedback.It is a pity to levy rates to counter any perceived competitive impact , consequently suppressing some of the innovation and enterprise that a mature sector needs to stay healthy.
So why bother?
Tourism has boomed in New Zealand and around the world. The question is how much we want to participate in that boom. Here’s what Statistics NZ estimates tourism was worth to New Zealand in the year ending March 2017:[3]
·
Total expenditure $36.0 billion;
·
International tourism expenditure $14.5 billion;· Domestic tourism expenditure $21.4 billion;
· Direct contribution to GDP: $14.7 billion (5.9% of NZ GDP);
· Indirect value added of industries supporting tourism $11.3 billion (4.6% of NZ GDP);
· 230,793 people directly employed in tourism (8.4% of NZ employment);
· $3.3 billion in goods and services taxes.
This is a business worth maintaining and hgrowing.
More detailed 2016 figure indicate that spending was close to $1,000
for every international visitor night recorded.
The guests in Airbnb and Book-a-Bach may spend a little less, and many
of them will be New Zealanders, but surely we don’t want to exclude participation
by home-based providers in a sector that returns so much to the country.
Tourism in Auckland
How about tourists in Auckland?
How about tourists in Auckland?
Here are some figures from the
ATEED website. There was an estimated 7.32m
guest nights in commercial accommodation in the year ending June 2018, based on
a total of 5.59m domestic overnight visits and 2.69m international arrivals. Their estimated spend of $8.36bn in the
region must have done a fair bit to sustain Auckland businesses and their rates
payments, on top of a Goods & Services Tax contribution of over $1bn .
Conclusion
The Council is wasting resources and political capital on chasing a minor sum that will discourage a valuable activity on the fringes of our visitor sector.
The Council is wasting resources and political capital on chasing a minor sum that will discourage a valuable activity on the fringes of our visitor sector.
If it really wants to play in the tourist pool, why not lobby
government to splash out a share of all the GST that visitors generate in
Auckland.
Or else simply be grateful for the support visitors give to the retail, entertainment, and hospitality sectors, and continue to collect rates from the properties and businesses they support. But think again about implementing a bad tax to fund a promotional agency, ATEED, with revenue of $84.6m in 2017 (up 37% on 2016), 83% of which is in any case funded by grants and subsidies (up 29% on 2016) primarily provided by the ratepayer.
Or else simply be grateful for the support visitors give to the retail, entertainment, and hospitality sectors, and continue to collect rates from the properties and businesses they support. But think again about implementing a bad tax to fund a promotional agency, ATEED, with revenue of $84.6m in 2017 (up 37% on 2016), 83% of which is in any case funded by grants and subsidies (up 29% on 2016) primarily provided by the ratepayer.
[2]
The Council is not sure what
the take will be from a commercial
bed tax, although it appears that last years collection was just over
$13m.
[3] Satellite
Tourism Accounts 2017, Statistics NZ, p7