The Quest
In March 2012 central government launched a multifaceted
reform programme, Better Local Government. The aim is to
“refocus” local councils in the interests of improving governance, efficiency,
and management. It identified eight areas for action:
- refocus the purpose of local government;
- introduce additional fiscal responsibility requirements;
- strengthen governance provisions;
- streamline reorganisation procedures;
- establish a local government efficiency task force;
- develop a framework for central/local government regulatory roles;
- investigate the efficiency of local government infrastructure provision;
- review the use of development contributions.
Better Local
Governance?
The programme is reductionist – breaking reform down into separate
parts as if they can be acted on independently. The risk is that the sum of the
various initiatives adds up to something less than a satisfactory whole.
For a start, none of the seven subsequent objectives can be
considered independently of the first.
The recently issued Local Government Act 2002 Amendment Bill
pursues their integration by introducing a new purpose statement. This seems a reasonable approach (whether or not the purpose statement is reasonable). The purpose should shape local government funding needs, governance, and management ; determine how it allocates and manages its resources; and influence
what it regulates, and how.
Promoting the Bill as the first step in the reform process also
seems to take care of the first four objectives. It offers the prospect of containing and
streamlining what local government does, informed about how it might best
do those things by the four reviews promised in the second four objectives.
Or More Central
Direction?
The bill will change the purpose of the Act from providing for :
local authorities to play a broad role in promoting the social, economic, environmental, and cultural well-being of their communities, taking a sustainable development approach (Part 1, 3 (d)).
to:
local authorities to play a broad role in meeting the current and future needs of their communities
for good-quality local infrastructure, local public services, and performance of regulatory functions
Reintroducing statutory limits to curb council (and community) discretion at the outset of the reform process risks pre-empting what might emerge from those reviews. The Bill requires local government to focus on functions that only it can perform. This return to basics means that councils might only act where markets fail or where they can demonstrate collective benefits sufficient to justify local public action . This is a step back from accountability -- because council hands are tied -- and consequently from community democracy. It moves us closer to the strait-jacket 1974 Act that the 2002 Act was intended to unbind. .
local authorities to play a broad role in promoting the social, economic, environmental, and cultural well-being of their communities, taking a sustainable development approach (Part 1, 3 (d)).
to:
local authorities to play a broad role in meeting the current and future needs of their communities
for good-quality local infrastructure, local public services, and performance of regulatory functions
Reintroducing statutory limits to curb council (and community) discretion at the outset of the reform process risks pre-empting what might emerge from those reviews. The Bill requires local government to focus on functions that only it can perform. This return to basics means that councils might only act where markets fail or where they can demonstrate collective benefits sufficient to justify local public action . This is a step back from accountability -- because council hands are tied -- and consequently from community democracy. It moves us closer to the strait-jacket 1974 Act that the 2002 Act was intended to unbind. .
The inference is that since the 2002 Act councils have acted
too broadly. With only a small number of
exceptions (the larger councils stand out in this respect), this is highly debatable.
Other provisions of the current Bill further reassert central over
local authority. These include scope for setting prudential standards or benchmarks
by Order in Council and much strengthened powers for the Minister to intervene
in the affairs of councils considered to be “struggling”.
Ironically, the provision also introduced in the Bill for elected councillors to dictate
staffing and remuneration policy increases the likelihood that councils will
“struggle”, confusing roles and reducing executive accountability. And allowing mayors more power in running
their councils – which may be a worthwhile measure in its own right
– is
unlikely to offset the increased exposure to governance failure. In practice, tinkering
with mayoral powers while limiting what councils might do may simply lift the tendency evident in our largest authorities towards
divided councils and sectional alliances.
Is this the thin edge
of the amalgamation wedge?
Perhaps the biggest concern for me is the much greater weight
given by the Bill to restructuring. Unlike the reforms of 1989, which were geared towards increasing the effectiveness of local government by doing
away with the redundancy, duplication, inefficiency, and excessive overheads of
a fragmented, hide-bound system, the objective of these
measures is not clear. Lurking
behind them, I suspect, is a commitment to further amalgamations, encouraged by
provision for applications for
restructuring rather than proposals.
A preoccupation with amalgamation again raises the spectre of
a solution
looking for a problem. The evidence that better governance or enhanced efficiencies
are delivered by larger units of local government is decidedly mixed.
Internationally research suggests that efficiencies may be increased by moving
from very small to medium-sized units of local government. But there is little
evidence that moving from medium to large units will deliver the goods.
Certainly
I have seen no evidence to support such an approach across the board in New
Zealand. It doesn’t exist in the
Department of Internal Affairs Regulatory
Impact Assessment for the current Bill, which acknowledges an aim to
facilitate more interests and more communities moving on the “union or
abolition of councils or the creation of unitary authorities” (Paragraph 158).
Technical efficiencies
may be available from merging, sharing, or jointly purchasing particular functions
or services across jurisdictions. That hardly requires amalgamations. And there is scant evidence of administrative efficiencies. Mergers that lead to multiple tiers of management
simply pile up the challenges of internal and cultural alignment within
enlarged bureaucracies already struggling to engage with their communities.
The Auckland
Experiment – too soon to tell?
In New Zealand’s case we should at least wait to see if the
Auckland Experiment works. The Local Government
Auckland Council Act (2009) sought to create a bigger, more influential, and more
effective council from the eight that went before.
Maybe it’s too early to judge the success or otherwise of
this experiment. However, there are sufficient disquieting signs to
suggest that the Government should make haste somewhat more slowly elsewhere.
For example, the
operating budget for Auckland Council in 2012/13 is $2.8 billion compared with the collective 2008/09 operating
expenditure of the eight councils identified of $1.95
billion (see Royal Commission Report Appendix
B). Spending growth of
45% (or $721m in 2009 dollars) compares with just 8% inflation between 2009 and
2012. Transition costs alone can’t explain
such a jump in costs - the Royal Commission suggested that at most transition would cost just $60 million a year for four years.
So
much for operating and administrative efficiencies from amalgamation. What
about capital expenditure?
I have not compared collective capital expenditure
by the prior councils with the plans of the new council. However, I have
already raised doubts grounded in the evidence for Auckland over the Council’s
planned capital programme. This is marked by an over-emphasis on the CBD and the $2-3billion it is
throwing at an underground rail connection, the benefits from which are
both constrained and uncertain. That central
government does not accept the arguments put forward by Auckland Council to
justify this investment (despite the $500m already committed to the electrification
necessary for under-grounding) is evident in its reluctance to support
the proposed rail connection financially.
The Risks of Amalgamations
These
question-marks over Auckland’s capital programme highlight serious questions
over the allocative efficiency of larger councils (and, as we often see in the
private sector, of large corporations generally).
The
creation of oversized municipalities does away with the sorts of checks and
balances associated with medium-sized councils.
It raises the spectre of single minded spending of larger budgets on ever
more ambitious – and unrealistic
– pet projects. Bigger councils with bigger budgets but the
same old thinking risk serious misallocation of finite public funds. And allocative inefficiency is a greater
threat to aggregate productivity with more far reaching consequences than any operating
inefficiencies that might be associated with smaller organisations.
A more cautious
approach to restructuring, an approach which encourages modest reform and puts barriers in
the way of building large, bureaucracies remote from their task environments may be called for. I suspect that the Auckland Experiment will
demonstrate sooner rather than later that restructuring is not the silver
bullet that will put an end to run-away council costs – or run away councils.
Seeking out Efficiencies
Better Local Government also sets the stage for an expert group to advise the Government on
how best to deliver good quality infrastructure at an economic cost. We need this advice on how to achieve better allocative efficiency before going too far down
the track on local government reform generally.
This call for best practice in policy analysis and the decisions that sit behind infrastructure investment regardless of council size. Improvements in allocative decisions may well be available before committing to the costs and uncertainties inherent in council amalgamations.
This call for best practice in policy analysis and the decisions that sit behind infrastructure investment regardless of council size. Improvements in allocative decisions may well be available before committing to the costs and uncertainties inherent in council amalgamations.
Operating
efficiencies might be gleaned from improved process, procedures, training,
investment, and, ultimately, purchasing. Administrative efficiencies might be
husbanded through moderating the size of councils. But don't expect to make big gains in this area, especially if, in doing so, we further weaken the local government labour market.
It’s
early days yet, but it seems that the advice that emerges from any expert investigation should inform any local government reforms, suggesting
that the Bill is premature within the wider programme.
Similarly, it seems premature to promote restructuring while
the Local
Government Efficiency Taskforce is only now looking at how to streamline consultation,
planning, and financial reporting. Equally, the New Zealand
Productivity Commission has only just commenced its inquiry
into what regulations are best developed and administered at local government level.
Resource Management Review
Something
else that bothers me about the Local Government Act 2002 Amendment Bill and how it is clearing the way for
amalgamation is what happens to the environment under unitary councils?
Again
we have some experience here, and I would expect to see it brought to bear in
the reform process.
Prior to the 1989 reform of local government and the 1991
Resource Management Act it was all too easy for the environmental gamekeeper to
also be the environmental poacher. We need to be aware of the risks of this
happening again. How far, I wonder, is
the Technical Advisory Group exploring options for
streamlining the RMA (convened by the Minister for the Environment) able to do
so in the face of parallel initiatives likely to change both the shape and practice
of local government in New Zealand?
Make haste slowly
There
may well be merit in the wider programme of reforms the government has
instituted, especially in the context of its economic development mandate. But it seems important that multiple
programmes and initiatives do not lead to conflicting outcomes. An enthusiasm to reform – and restructure
– local
government should not pre-empt the efficiencies that might be achieved by
simply boosting the quality of decision-making. Only when we have examined how infrastructure,
regulation, and resource management might be delivered most effectively will we
really know what sort of reforms might be needed in local (and central) government.
2 comments:
A very sensible analysis of events. I do note that over ten years ago it was obvious that the reducing world resources and our civilisation's overwhelming need for oil would directly impact on local government. This seemed likely to eventualy drive central government intervention. Local government operations have a large energy/oil input and is a key driver behind greater than CPI inflation for this industry. Local government could therefore be expected to be reformed in response to increasing resentment by society on costs being passed on through rates and fees.
In addition, charges have risen from new costs associated with the expectation and requirement to apply modern technologies to improve levels of service such as water and sewerage treatment. Eventually service levels of local government will need to drop to maintain affordability, essentially as our civilsation peaks and then declines. I suspect that we are now within that period of debate and this debate is closely aligned with the prices of energy commodities.
I do note that an almost insane drive for growth in population in Auckland (rather than happiness!) seems to be a major factor in the need for the disproportionate* investment in long term assets in Auckland over the rest of NZ (*excluding Christchurch that needs to be rebuilt). The only surprise really is the "shoot first, ask questions later" approach by the Government, but that is often the way of politicians.
Thanks, Anonymous. One of the problems is local government is full of contradictions. It talks sustainability and even tries to regulate residents to behave in responsible (if misinformed) ways with respect to resource consumption while becoming ever more voracious in its own spending. Gold-plating infrastructure, spending money on iconic but ultimately over-engineered and underutilised iconic amenities (monumentalism), opting for big bang projects and silver bullets instead of incremental improvements and the pursuit of best practice outcomes run counter to sensible fiscal and resource policies.
The problem with central government assuming responsibility for fixing local problems or providing local public goods, or combining councils, is a loss of accountability and transparency. Bigger agencies simply result in more waste and less flexibility.
Post a Comment